Truck and Barter Where Sympathy and Hedonism Collide |
BY
Ian
Experiments in Risk Valuation: The Game of Infected Chicken
If you can't get ahead of an outbreak, I suppose another solution is to attempt to stop concerns about the outbreak itself. Avian flu looks like it might grow from a moderate to a prominent problem in China, as well as Vietnam and Indonesia.
First, of course, is the issue of Thailand having quickly decided that the value of a life is roughly 3 million baht. While we might expect that there were considerable non-use value, willingness-to-pay, and various other calculations used to devise this number, I'd guess it was done more along the lines of a car-part recall. The percentage of chickens that could possibly carry the virus, times the proportion of the population that eats chicken, times the probability of an infected person dying (not the chances of someone being infected -- payoff only occurs when someone dies), times the value of a possible lawsuit including a discount factor for the amount of time left in the average working person's life...and, well, you get the idea. Morbid, certainly, but it seems like the better way for Thailand to find an affordable value, quickly.
I'm sure that comes as a relief for those few people whose human-to-chicken dinner ratio is a positive number.
1/31/2004 03:54:47 AM
BY
Kevin
Wise Debt Choices Economists at the New York Fed--including the straight-talking Dick Peach and Meg McConnell, with whom I worked for a year after undergraduate school--looked into what exactly homeowners were doing by refinancing and home equity loans (press accounts here and here). Their results are summarized in "After the Refinancing Boom: Will Consumers Scale Back Their Spending?" Their answer, no! Basically, they find that consumers have responded to low mortgage rates by substituting mortgage debt for high interest rate nonmortage debt (credit cards, etc.). Consumers are not historically overwhelmed by debt. I quote their conclusion in full, but the entire paper is worth your time, if you're willing to think about the national accounts:
It's too bad I had to leave the NY Fed... I really like the research they do.
1/30/2004 08:21:27 PM
BY
Kevin
The Learning Curve of Death I just learned through this 2002 paper in the NEJM that there has been a long-standing supposition by medical care analysts that the higher the rate of procedures performed in a hospital, the lower the mortality rate of the patients. This suggests that the graphically inclined might be able to draw a learning curve for which the expected mortality (cost) of producing an additional unit decreases considerably with each additional unit (until it flattens out). That paper pointed to this book, published by the National Academy of Science, which insists, after examination of 88 volume-outome studies, that this learning curve is real. They reproduce one chart, also printed here, and note that:
To me, enacting government policies to efficiently take advantage of this relationship will be very difficult. First because "[a]vailable data suggest that significant numbers of patients do not use data on outcomes or volume where they exist to choose where to receive care." So it's left to suppliers and insurance companies to make medical procedures less deadly, even in the face of consumer-patients who are at best indifferent to the shift towards high-volume care, and might perhaps be hostile to it.
1/30/2004 03:11:20 PM
BY
Kevin
Saturn: An Unprofitable Kind of Company This requires no comment:
Those interested should also see MotorTrend's take:
Even more available at Dave Leggett's just-auto.com blog.
1/30/2004 01:42:05 PM
BY
Kevin
For now, "Reverse Urban Sprawl" The New York Times' Josh Barbanel reports that in the boroughs outside of Manhattan, tremendous increases in housing prices have led private real estate developers to build multiple-family apartment buildings and condos where single-family homes or vacant lots once stood--even in communities previously considered blighted. But buried at the end we find out this won't last very long, as entreched interests, relatively unconcerned about the welfare of new immigrants, fight back:
1/30/2004 01:01:11 PM
BY
Dragos
Being an entrepreneur Rob over at BusinessPundit makes a very interesting comment about what it takes to be an entrepreneur these days, making an analogy between being a paranoid and being entrepreneurial. He starts from Andy Groves' "Only the Paranoid Survive" and says: "[...]...I assume when he (Grove) speaks of paranoia he is implying that you shouldn't let your guard down. Most paranoid people I know who are in business (as opposed to the ones who are locked up - just kidding) constantly think something bad is about to happen. They think their competitors are conspiring to spring something new on them, customers or employees are planning to suddenly leave, the economy is about to tank, or something similarly bad is going to happen. My paranoia stems from a different place. Like Grove and others, I am paranoid that I will be wrong about the outcome of a certain decision or the direction of a trend. But my paranoia comes one layer before theirs. I am paranoid about my perceptions." As such, an entrepreneur has to be a "paranoid" in the sense of challenging all the steps from the thinking process along the strategy formation and implementation. As an entrepreneur myself, I think that besides the good practices Rob talks about, one has to be patient, stubborn and perseverent. Of course you will have to be agile and flexible in terms of admitting and correcting your errors quick, but also be patient about seeing the fruits of your strategy, and perseverent in pursuing your goals/targets. An entrepreneur has tough decisions to make, and not only has to decide but also to execute well. Basically, most of the time it is an exercise of making decisions throughout all challenges and opportunities. It can be very rewarding - you create value, but also very risky - especially in the beginning, when the resource management is critical, and very enjoyable - you are in the position of seeding the organizational culture and choosing the guys you work with. Piece of advice: choose from the best, even though it might be more expensive, the returns are definitely higher. Finally, one will have to know himself/herself very well before starting a venture. Perhaps it is an ongoing process but I guess a good way of starting doing that is answering the following questions mentioned in Startup Journal (via Emergic):
1/29/2004 04:35:52 PM
BY
Kevin
Trust within the Firm Sam Brown, T&B's only connection to Oxford, recently posted a humorous summary of his new thesis topic--the consequences of Trust within a firm. He invites economists, bloggers, and former presidential candidates to rip it to shreds. Please help the man out. UPDATE: See also the second post right above the first, written by Sam's coblogger Simon.
1/29/2004 12:41:46 PM
BY
Ian
And Some Thought Butterfly-Ballots Were Problematic...
Since the voting post turned out pretty well before, let's get back to the subject for a moment, shall we? Specifically, the issue of "e-voting", or electronic voting through the use of electronic terminals, the internet, etc.
1/27/2004 08:31:54 PM
BY
Jamie
Free Trade Query
Paul Craig Roberts
continues his debate at the Mises Blog with a comprehensive response to all of the feedback he continues to receive from his recent alliance with Senator Schumer. I have given Mr. Roberts the benefit of doubt, reading carefully what he has had to say, including an earlier article relating to this subject. Mr. Roberts' concern may be sincere, however, his arguments are circular. George Reisman's essay along with others, remain a formidable response to Roberts (though it seems as if they are, philosophically, speaking different languages). One question has been troubling me since this entire debate began - Is this an intellectually valid debate? Two small items to consider:
1/26/2004 08:54:40 PM
BY
Cardozo
T&B welcomes Cardozo Bozo Hello all! I have taken up Kevin's offer to blog with T&B. I am a law student at Benjamin N. Cardozo School of Law in Manhattan and I live on Wall St. (yes, really) I had my own blog here, but with the new semester starting up I figured I would not have time to post regularly. I'm really looking forward to contributing, and hope to get something in at least once, maybe twice a week. And don't worry! I'll proof-read my work from now on, promise! You can follow the link to see some of my old posts(please forgive the spelling and grammar). I think they will introduce me as well as anything I can say here - and won't waste T&B's front-page time...
1/25/2004 07:42:39 PM
BY
Dragos
COO's outlook perspective Here is an interesting survey from Deloitte about some COO's perspective on the economic outlook, both on national and international levels. The surveyed COOs were from North America (USA and Canada), Europe (UK and Germany) and Asia Pacific (Japan and Australia). The survey was made last summer and released in October last year; apart from the Deloitte's comments, I think it is also worth mentioning (i)the American optimism about the 2004 US economic improvement (79%) as opposed to the Japanese one about their own (95% think it will be worse or the same); (ii)the German concern about the development of the national political environment as a strong influencer on their business (60%); and (iii)the relative overall optimism about the company performance improvement (above 60%) with revenue growth and cost reduction as being equally important on average. (big surprise, heh?) However it is interesting that the US COOs place more emphasis on revenue growth by considering a better penetration of existing customers (77%) and expanding current markets with current products (72%) while German COOs view developing new products as a more important revenue growth. This doesn't stop the Europe’s brain drain whereas the best scientific minds are leaving for droves to USA.
1/25/2004 06:15:09 AM
BY
Jamie
Yet Another New Face
Greetings from the West Coast of America. I appreciate Kevin's invitation to contribute to the Truck & Barter Blog. I must begin with the disclaimer that I do not posses the scholarly learning of the other bloggers on T & B - My education has been a self-taught affair - and is very much a work in-progress.
1/24/2004 04:10:25 PM
BY
Kevin
Paying for Health Insurance The amazing thing about newspaper reporters is their ability to find statistics that support their theories. In this case the theory is that healthcare costs may not decline when people "control their own care" (i.e. pay the marginal costs of their decisions). Michelle Andrews notes that no statistics exist to support or deny this theory, yet she proceeds to quote selective statistics anyway:
Excuse me, but there is a "question" whether employees are paying a greater share of health insurance premia, although there is "no question" that both employees and employers are paying more (and the latter getting more care). It is not true, which is implied but not stated, that since employees are paying more, employers are paying less. In fact, there is a solid basis to question the validity most of the numbers in Michelle Andrew's story. As I reported on September 10 of last year, the Kaiser Family Foundation's 2003 Employer Health Benefits Survey found that the employee share of premia is steady for family coverage at 27% and steady for single coverage at 16%. (This survey has consistent results going back to 1988). This is a far cry from the 57% for HMO premia and 56% for PPO premia reported by Mercer. See section 6 of the KFF report for all the data I'm talking about. (Note: I welcome comments from anybody who can figure out how the Mercer and Kaiser data can be reconciled.) But let's say Ms. Andrews data are right, and mine wrong. (I cannot confirm or refute her data, because they are from Mercer HR Consulting's Consumerism group, and must be purchased for $1,000 , which I refuse to do for a blog post). Mercer's data would still indicate that healthcare spending (i.e. price*quantity) has increased so much that employers are paying more too. However, they're shifting more of the burden of such increases onto employee-consumers than onto themselves. To the employer, health insurance cost increases are no different that a raise in the employee's salary. Worries that lower income employees might be receiving (or might choose to receive) inferior care have let to some counterintuitive corporate policies:
If I were a high-paid employee, I'd push back. Basically this company increased health benefits for lower-wage employees and decreased them for higher-wage employees. No mention is made of any salary adjustments that have been or will be made. Is it just possible that after enacting this plan, lower-wage employees will receive lower salary increases and higher-wage employees will receive higher salary increases? If so, are lower-wage employees really better off?
1/24/2004 08:43:08 AM
BY
Kevin
Offline Content The American Society of Magazine Editors reports the number of magazines by category, as compiled in the National Directory of Magazines. (Data are broken into 1988-1998, and 1999-2003).
While the early data are probably underestimates, as a number of the 283 categories, like Sound Engineering, Vending Machines, Physics, Baseball, and a lot of others weren't reported until 1992. However, the recent decline--the number of magazines was 23.5% lower in 2003 than in 2001--are not the result of falling response rates of statistical glitches; instead they represent a real trend downward in the thickness of certain markets. But this does not mean that all magazine producers are fairing worse--just most. Only 18 categories had net gains in the number of magazines since 2001:
Survival & Weapons* However, the variance in the number of magazines published annually in each cateogry is fairly large. For only 8 categories (marked with asterisks) was 2003 their best year ever. Paint magazines tied for their best year. I console myself by saying only the marginal magazines folded, that more pulp is not always better pulp, and I suppose that the shift from offline to online content might be able to explain much of this slump in aggregate magazine supply.
1/22/2004 02:46:30 PM
BY
Ian
Quick Shot Across the Bow
No real commentary about this, but I wanted to toss up a link to a fascinating paper on health care purchasing. You can find it at NBER with this link. I was going to put it in a comment, but then realized, hey, more people should read it than might look at the comments...
1/22/2004 12:05:26 PM
BY
Dragos
Another new face I am also new around and I am glad Kevin accepted my offer to write for T&B. My interests lie within strategy and technology, and I will try to offer a different perspective considering that I will be blogging mostly from Eastern Europe (Bucharest, Romania), where things are definitely approached with different twists and turns. Will get back soon.
1/22/2004 11:16:12 AM
BY
Kevin
Still an Open Invitation We want more econobloggers on T&B. If you or someone you know wants to blog about economics--even part-time or occasionally--please send me an email. Don't not let your reluctance get the best of you. Everyone who applies will be accepted. There is no interview or review process. You don't need experience in blogging or commenting. You don't need an advanced education in economics, or even a formal education in anything. But you do need to write seriously about economics or related subjects.
1/22/2004 09:05:29 AM
BY
Kevin
Reforming Healthcare: Cost vs. Price Last June, I wrote my favorite post--The Quantity and Quality of Healthcare. I still defend my basic assertion--that the quantity and quality of healthcare produced and consumed by Americans has dramatically increased over the past several generations, and continues to increase. The remarkable continually-increasing effectiveness of modern healthcare is the primary driver of our ever-higher spending on healthcare. To put this assertion differently: as the total cost of healthcare has gone up, its real price has gone down. The problem with making this case is that the official data (the Bureau of Economic Analysis detailed NIPA statistics), seem to contradict it in several important ways. After all, if we look at the official aggregate data over the past 40 years, we see that not only is the growth rate of total spending on healthcare enormous, but that its decomposition into price dwarfs its decomposition into quantity:
Accounting for population increases, the conventional measures show that in 2003, Americans purchased a hell of lot more medical care per person than in 1960--over 4 times as much medical care per person. However, the price of that medical care has risen 11 times as high as in 1960. (These are derived from the numbers on the chart, but not on the chart themselves). The data seem to lead to the conclusion that we're buying much more healthcare, but at sky-high prices. However, economists who know what they're talking about (i.e. not me), doubt the validity and applicability of the offical data--primarily because it does not appropriately adjust for quality. Our poor data does not provide an adequate picture of the diverse composite of services we call "healthcare" or "medical care", and policymakers should be weary of cost-combating healthcare reforms until somebody understands better the actual consequences of reform efforts. Being a healthcare economics greenhorn when I wrote the original post (I'm still green), I had no idea just how much I was merely restating previously published research. For instance, Robert F. Graboyes, in his 1994 paper "Medical Care Price Indexes." demonstrates just how difficult it is to create a medical care price index that adjusts for quality change. In the paper, he presents a very simple example of a quality change that would not be seen by official data: Say an advance in a medical procedure increases the percent of patients who survive it from 10% to 30%. This induces the number of patients who undergo the procedure annually to increase from 1000 to 2000, even though the price of the medical procedure increases from $500 to $600. The official statistics will see a $100 (20%) increase in price of the medical procedure, but the average price of one life saved drops from $5,000 to $2,000 (-60%). This example assumes that not dying from a procedure should count as a quality increase, which I think more appropriate than the status-quo assumption that not dying shouldn't count as a quality increase. Such quality increases are sometimes but rarely included in the official data, although attempts to analyze specific procedures are ongoing. Many of these attempts are amassed in the 1999 Brookings volume "Measuring the Prices of Medical Treatments". The introductory essay by Jack Triplett and Ernst Berndt reaffirms my view that much caution should be taken by healthcare reformists of all parties:
Also, I recently found out that Dr. Rangel agrees with the quantity/quality theory:
Now that healthcare "costs" are again a popular topic of conversation, totaling 15% of GDP, and rising at shocking or extraordinary rates (9.3% being the latest zinger), I find it necessary to criticize the notion that rising expenditures are undesirable and wasteful. Why is 15% of GDP inefficient? Is any other share of national output better? Perhaps 6%, 8%, or 10% as occurs in other developed countries? Except in clear cases of fraud or wasteful procedures, I have seen no proof that the resources spent providing healthcare in the United States would be better employed elsewhere in the economy. I don't believe that American cardiologists would suggest that all the extra care now provided to heart attack patients should be stopped, either because the Europeans use fewer resources and have similar outcomes, or because the resources are better used on say, cancer patients. I have ignored and will continue to ignore the payment systems--government and private--that change the way medical care costs are perceived: by making it worthwhile for producers provide too much care (or the wrong type of care) to consumers who demand more (or rarely refuse it), and do not have to pay for it. It may be that our big social "problem"--spending too much on healthcare--derives mostly from the very measures and structures that policymakers would like to strengthen. But before attacking these structures, I'd prefer that the professionals understand which services Americans are consuming more of, and distinguish them from the parts undergoing large quality-adjusted price inflation. UPDATE: Read this piece by Don Peck in the Atlantic online. He defines "the problem" better than I could. Also, he advocates a system of lower quality growth in a tradeoff for more equality of care--a massive intervention that I cannot endorse:
1/21/2004 04:09:24 PM
BY
Ian
Philip Morris Plays a Subgame?
I can't imagine the folks over at Philip Morris are happy about having to announce that they're "willing to chat" about regulation of marketing. After all, it's accepting restrictions on their future abilities.
1/21/2004 12:31:09 PM
BY
Ian
Political Econoblogging: There's Something About Borda
1/19/2004 09:45:21 PM
BY
Ian
New Face
Just a quick note to say a public thanks to Kevin for accepting my note in response to his "Open Invitation".
1/17/2004 11:12:13 AM
BY
Kevin
Inflation, the Minimum Wage, and Real Progress Still inspired by Greg Easterbrook's outrage (see the post below), and spurred the availability of microdata, I here graph the December 1997, 1999, 2001, and 2003 Current Population Survey wage data for full-time workers and, separately, for part-time workers. What I want to look at is the impact of a constant nominal minimum wage ($5.15) on the distribution of real wages. So I used the BLS CPI-U to deflate 1999, 2001, and 2003 by the appropriate amounts, giving me 1999, 2001, and 2003 wages in 1997 dollars (i.e. it made those wages smaller numbers). Let's take a look:
For both full-time and part-time workers, inflation has caused a decrease in the real minimum wage, from $5.15 in 1997 to $4.94 (1999) to $4.70 (2001) to $4.51 (2003) in 1997 dollars. Yet median real wages, for those who make up to $10 per hour (1997 dollars), have steadily increased since 1997. In every succeeding year, we see a spreading of both distributions toward the lower real minimum wage. But this trend downward is outmatched by another trend upward--a shift in the entire distribution towards a higher median real wage. NOTE: No more posts today, nor will I be responding to email or comments. I must focus on studying for the Law and Economics preliminary exam, which is being administered tomorrow at 9am.
1/16/2004 11:22:07 AM
BY
Kevin
The Percent of People in Low-Wage Jobs Greg Easterbrook writes;
Unfortunately, Mr. Easterbook has not given any information about the extent of the problem of too-low wages. The minimum wage may or may not be a national scandal (I have no desire at this point to discuss the impacts of increasing the minimum wage), but I wanted to point out that not only it is necessary to look at the level of the minimum wage, it is necessary to look at the number of people or the percent of the population that actually earn the minimum wage (or less, if they're off the books). Only with such information will I know how relevant the minimum wage is to the economy. Unfortunately, such information is really hard to obtain, so I'll do my best to illuminate the issue with what I have at my disposal. What do the data say? First, to Mr. Easterbrook's concern: Data from the Economic Policy Institute on the value of the real minimum wage show a decrease similar to the one he points out:
The "national scandal" is plain to see. The minimum wage has been moving around the same real average of $5 since 1987, after being around $6.50 for a very long time. Compare that to the chart of real wages for production workers as a whole.
This implies that a minimum-wage worker of today is, in both an absolute and relative sense, worse off than a minimum wage-worker was in 1963. I'll let that stand, although I think this really ignores the real-cost reductions in many goods consumed by the poor, and the explosion of low-cost consumer options. But the question remains, what is the distribution of actual hourly wages today compared to Mr. Easterbrook's favorite 1963? The data of how many people earned which hourly wages in 1963 is not readily available to me, but I can show the distribution for December 2003. According to Current Population Survey microdata (obtained via Ferrett), the distribution of hourly wages, for those who worked part-time or full-time in December 2003, regardless of other circumstances, is as follows:
Vertical markers are at $5 and $7, horizontal at 5% and 10%. I cut off wages at $50 per hour, and made all those with more than $50 just equal $50. According to this graph, about 1.2% of full-timers earned less than or equal to $5.15 per hour, 3.4% of full-timers earn less than $6 per hour and 12% of full-timers made less than $7.50 per hour; however, about 6.3% of part-timers made less than or equal to the minimum wage, 20% of part-timers earn less than $6 per hour, and 44% of part-time workers make less than $7.50 per hour. In other words, a lot of workers are very distant from the minimum wage, some are within striking distance, and much fewer are held up by the price floor--for both part-time and full-time employment. What are these numbers for 1963? Are more people closer to the minimum wage, or are less? When I find them, I'll add them to the post. But since I do not yet have the older distribution, let me show some other data instead. The maximum real wage of the lowest 10%, 20% and 30% back till 1973 is courtesy of the Economic Policy Institute. It seems we're back in 1973, but that those real minimum wage drops haven't affected the lowest 10% of income earners nearly as much as Mr. Easterbrook might think, because even the bottom 10% earns above the minimum:
NOTE: I haven't tried to adjust for inflation between 2000 and 2003, which will change the numbers slightly. Also, a previous version of this post was mistakenly published without proofreading and other important changes. Apologies from T&B.
1/15/2004 01:18:56 PM
BY
Kevin
KB Toys - Chapter 11 Bankrupt To me, after visiting one of those horrid, temporary KB Toys Express stores, this outcome seemed inevitable.
In other words, other retailers predicted customer desires much better than KB, and did so cost-effectively.
1/14/2004 01:25:44 PM
BY
Kevin
An Open Invitation Have you ever considered blogging about economics? If you have, and want to give it a shot, you should know that I'm opening up shop for newcomers. Anybody who wants to econoblog--even if I don't know you--is welcome to join T&B. Just email me, and I'll set you up. I have no idea if T&B readers who don't already blog are at all interested in writing, but this seems like a pretty good means of finding out. Perhaps nobody will answer my call because everybody who wants to blog can already do so costlessly (a Chicago-style argument). But perhaps supply is limited because of high start-up or maintenance costs, fear of failure, or risk aversion. Also, I want to point out the newly created Wealth & Power econoblog by Shane Trimble. "a 33 year old student, pursuing a B.A. in Economics at Carleton University." There's not much econ content up there yet, but he's in Canada, and "What else can you when it's 20 below outside but blog?" Good luck, Shane, and keep warm.
1/14/2004 12:54:29 PM
BY
Kevin
How to Determine My Ideology Somebody just hit T&B from a Google search of private markets undersupply public goods, in which T&B ranks fourth. But if you search Google for private markets don't undersupply public goods, T&B ranks first. Note that I don't necessarily agree with Google; I just think that over- or under- first-best analysis isn't what economics should be about.
1/14/2004 12:05:18 PM
BY
Kevin
Open Question The cost of establishing a moon base and going to Mars is debatable. But what is the Return on Investment for establishing a moon base? How are we to judge this government program from an efficiency perspective? Arguably, government should be pursuing programs with a really high positive ROI that the private sector, for various reasons, will not produce. If time permits, I should have some thoughts later...
1/14/2004 11:37:08 AM
BY
Kevin
Errors in Economic Forecasting Most economists recognize that for any economic prediction, some average of forecasts exists that is consistently more accurate than any specific forecasting model. Although most American business reporters don't seem to understand this, the Swiss are on the ball, and actually report multiple forecasts, and interview economists who doubt the accuracy of offical numbers. Yes, a rough confidence interval is a good idea:
1/13/2004 04:42:55 PM
BY
Kevin
This swissinfo article about security to protect the next World Economic Forum dicusses the enormous cost of protecting the economic elite:
Half the budget! Still this provides a new and interesting example for game theory:
Is there a social optimum here?
1/13/2004 09:50:00 AM
BY
Kevin
Following the Election I will be following the 2004 U.S. Presidential election at Kikuchiyo News. My first post in that regard charts the number of sensible economic proposals made by each of the candidates.
1/12/2004 01:12:24 PM
BY
Kevin
Carnival of the Capitalists This week's Carnival, featuring the week's very best recent economics and business blogging, is up at Ensight. I especially liked the Jonathan Gewirtz post on "Customer Service" vs. Real Service. Choice quote:
1/12/2004 12:43:19 PM
BY
Kevin
"That's freaking awesome!" Economists often make the point that racial discrimination by business firms requires them to use either more expensive or inferior quality labor--clearly hurting the bottom line. There are exceptions to this rule: for instance, when customers uniformly prefer a segregated atmosphere, their markets are "best served" by racist companies. (Think all-white Southern lunch counters). But the pressure on public companies for maximium shareholder value, in an era where the ethnicity of most producers is either not seen by or irrelevant to consumers, means racism is usually shunned, leading to racial mixing that I found rather comforting:
1/12/2004 12:31:59 PM
BY
Kevin
T&B in The Washington Times A couple of weeks ago I was interviewed by Christian Toto for this piece about student blogging in The Washington Times. I didn't know the article was going to feature me front and center.
What does it mean to write like a blogger? Being accurate, aggressive, honest, fair, and humble. The author made me sound clear and intelligible--which I wasn't during the interview. My preferred answers to Mr. Toto's questions were written to him in an email, but WaTimes policy is not to conduct interviews over email. But being a blogger gives me the last word on the subject, so here were Mr. Toto's questions and my response:
1/12/2004 09:46:09 AM
BY
Kevin
University Economics for Children
This article on swissinfo.org describes the attempt of Prof. Dr. Franz Jaeger of St. Gallen University in Basel to give a lecture entitled "Where does money come from?" to a group of 650 nine to twelve year olds:
"This is open to all children from all backgrounds and from all schools," university rector Peter Gomez told swissinfo, stressing that the university was not targeting over-achievers.
"We think that topics such as business, economics and law - our core disciplines - are hugely underestimated in schools. No one tells children how these work..."
The children may have been excited, but for economics professor Franz Jaeger the lecture was a terrifying prospect.
"In all my years as a lecturer, I’ve never had so much stage fright as today," Jaeger told swissinfo ahead of the event.
It was indeed a daunting sight, with a sea of children gazing down expectantly to the front of the auditorium, pencils poised.
Luckily, Jaeger soon won them over with the help of colourful illustrations projected onto a screen as he explained that money did not grow on trees, but had to be earned by mums and dads.
But the initial attentiveness began to wear off after Jaeger raced into the complexities of state funding, pensions and taxes.
1/11/2004 02:02:40 PM
BY
Kevin
Public Choice Tomorrow I take my field exam in public choice; expect no blogging until then. Now I'm going home and getting a good night's rest--until the baby wakes me up, that is. (The interested may test themselves with earlier versions of the Public Choice exam here). For bonus points, "Outline Tullock's 1980 model of efficient rent seeking" in the comments section.
1/9/2004 11:02:13 PM
BY
Kevin
A Reminder I'll be posting on non-economic issues over at Kikuchiyo News. My two most recent posts discuss Chechnya as Vietnam and Bridge Bucks.
1/9/2004 04:47:45 PM
BY
Kevin
Does Kaus read T&B? Not a chance. But in this entry yesterday, he picked out the same sentence in a Howard Dean speech that T&B pointed out on December 19. That sentence, be it only targeted propaganda, deserves repeating for its lack of recognition of inidividuals:
It is time for us to spell out a new social contract a fundamental renegotiation of the rights and responsibilities of the critical actors in the American economy: families, corporations and government.
1/9/2004 02:29:31 PM
BY
Kevin
Bad Satire: Poverty is the Solution Foreigners are the enemy, and fully impoverishing the enemy is the most effective solution to our economic crisis. Two recent hot topics of the econoblogosphere--immigration reform and free-trade--have solicited much radical enlightened opinion against foreigners. Why? It's clear that their economic advance means American economic decline. Foreigners who've illegally entered our country make us poorer by living in our homes, taking our jobs, and lowering our incomes. In their own countries, foreigners take our capital, our education, and our jobs, always giving us less back than we give them. Since, left to our own self-interest, we foolishly allow illegals to live among as, and we persistently make trades that leave us worse off, we must use the government to prevent us from engaging the enemy. Contact with foreigners is a national prisoners dilemma; in the aggregate, we'd be better off if none of us had contact with foreigners, but given some Americans invariably do, the rest of us have an incentive to trade with, train, employ, and marry them. The government should cartelize contact with foreigners to prevent this free-rider problem. This cartel "solution" many have posed requires us to throw out all the illegals (and keep them out), and put up barriers to capital and information movement. We must not have free trade in people, capital or ideas. But isn't there a better solution? If Americans get poorer when foreigners get richer, shouldn't Americans get richer when foreigners get poorer? So why don't we try to make them as poor as possible? Won't that maximize our wealth? I leave aside the actual microeconomic and macroeconomic policy programs necessary to do this, but I'm sure our politicians can figure out cost-effective means of regulating our behavior.
I hasten to note that the writing above is bad satire. I don't have any specific commenter in mind, and I won't mis-characterize anybody as holding these hateful and ignorant views, although I think they're logical conclusions of a lot of what I've read recently.
1/9/2004 11:52:56 AM
BY
Kevin
Real-World Competition: Lowering Prices, Looking Ahead From a New York Times story indicating that US Airways will have to sell assets to stay competitive:
I do not want to believe that the post 9-11, post-bankruptcy operating plan of US Airways assumed no increase in competition, but evidently it did not. Did those in charge of US Air think that their low-cost competitors would just go away? Maybe not, but Southwest might be thinking that US Airways might just go away:
And why shouldn't Southwest? If Southwest sees US Airways--a legacy airline--as high-cost, high-priced, and barely meeting debt obligations, it should go for the jugular. Believe it or not, Southwest already dominates the Las Vegas market:
Southwest and "the independents" are geared towards making money in competitive markets--with all types of fares and demand--, and are succeeding wildly:
Another big market for independents is Fort Lauderdale, where an expanding number of small low-cost airlines are building a network of small cities that interconnect with the airport:
The latest addition is USA 3000, which claims to be low-cost and high-service:
Remember, non-price competition can be an efficient market outcome.
1/8/2004 09:40:29 PM
BY
Kevin
Updates to Free Trade Post I haven't written anything new, but other people have. Check out the 5 updates on the bottom of the Thoughts on Free Trade post below.
1/7/2004 09:32:06 PM
BY
Kevin
Playing with the Economy No more posting today. However, I've questioned the gallery at Steve Verdon's about the extent of the ability of governments to influence the economy, and our ability to figure out the consequences. I've also told the Chicago Boyz that currently the dollar may be weak, or it may be strong, but that I really don't know.
1/6/2004 03:58:54 PM
BY
Kevin
Rough First Draft: Thoughts on Free Trade
This excerpt is from an Op-Ed in today's New York Times by Senator Charles Schumer and Paul Craig Roberts. Since these men are not stupid, they use what I must conclude is an intentionally unclear analysis, to deny that benefits of free trade accrue to all, while calling for experts to "end the confusion between the free flow of goods and the free flow of factors of production." My first response was emotional--"Sirs, we are not confused between outputs and inputs; you are." But that's unfair and wrong. Let's give it some serious thought. Schumer and Roberts deny the applicability of the Ricardian theory of comparative advantage, which has long stipulated that free trade benefits all when everybody specializes in what they do best (given no capital or labor movement between nations and no information mobility except for prices). Schumer and Roberts do not refute the Ricardian model. Instead they deny that the Ricardian model fits the world we live in. They insist that in the modern world, "capital, technology and ideas" mixed with labor--i.e. "jobs"--move from high-cost to low-cost regions. The assert that each time a job moves from a high-cost region to a low-cost region, the high-cost region loses out to the low-cost region. Our authors write, "In this situation, there are no longer shared gains -- some countries win and others lose." But this is not quite correct. Entire regions don't win or lose, but individuals in those regions do, and in the aggregate, the entire world is more productive. If America is high-cost and developing nations low-cost, what happens is that American consumers are clearly better off, while some American producers are better off and some are worse off. And although Schumer and Roberts don't seem to care about foreigners, both foreign producers and foreign consumers are no worse off, and most likely better off. (Would they actively pursue a policy that made all foreigners worse off if it made all Americans better off?) So what happens in the modern post-Ricardian world? Assume regions produce identical goods--just at different cost. Let's take the case of the MRI, given that Schumer and Roberts are worried about American radiologists facing stiff competition from abroad. Say an American Radiologist makes $150K a year, while a comparable foreign worker is willing to be paid $25K, or 1/6 the price, because his other opportunities earn so little, and education is cheap. The question remains why the foreign doctor is willing to accept so much less. For if the foreign radiologist can really compete almost costlessly with the American, why doesn't he charge $125K a year or $145K a year, still undercutting his high-cost competitor? He would raise his price, but a lot of others outside America also charge $25K, eventually leading to a plunge in the price of a year's worth of a doctor's radiological services to $25K a year. [I'll leave aside what happens if few foreigners compete with Americans, because then Schumer and Roberts don't care.] First, let's talk about our American radiologist. Guess what, he's worse off. But nobody (i.e. no serious economist) denies that high-cost producers are worse off when they compete with low-cost producers. In fact, that warrants one big "duh!" What happens to our American radiologist? Well, he probably won't be examining MRIs for long , unless he can focus his practice specializing sn MRIs that need immediate analysis and cannot be sent overseas. How much is he worse off? Well if he remains a radiologist, he'll earn $25K a year, so his $125K loss is the same as consumers' $125K gain. But he will not remain a radiologist working for $25K, or he will never become a radiologist in the first place. Instead he will need to switch to a career offering better opportunities. This is harder for experienced radiologists, but experienced radiologists will not have much competition from abroad, given the limited number of experienced radiologists abroad. This involves a certain cost of retraining, yes. But there is a lot opportunity out there for former radiologists. In fact, there's more opporunity than without foreign competition. Why? Because there is a huge savings for Americans who consume MRIs. Consumers are clearly better off. Having the same service performed at 1/6 the cost, means that 5/6 is free to be spent elsewhere. This 125K will be saved or spent on other goods and services--presumably provided by former or never-to-be radiologists. By the way, although Schumer and Roberts don't write about it, nobody denies that our foreign doctor is better off. But what about the foreign consumer, now that all these foreign doctors are serving Americans? We'll, given that entry into radiology is competitive, foreign consumers are no worse off than they were before, as prices remain at still low opportunity costs. They might be better served by more expert radiologists. So low-cost nations are better off. UPDATE: Kikuchiyo throws a fireball:
UPDATE 2: Stephen Karlson has a lot to add:
UPDATE 3: Arnold Kling insists that the Ricardian Theory still applies:
UPDATE 4: Don Boudreaux (now at Mises Blog?!?) notes a pretty big factual error made by Schumer and Roberts:
Ouch. Somebody needs to check his quotes. Note that Professor Roy J. Ruffin is not David Ricardo. Also, it is interesting to note that Mises Blog published a post from Paul Craig Roberts on this very topic on August 8, 2003. (Dan Mahoney responded two weeks later). You can follow the entire exchange here. UPDATE 5: Kyle Markley (Cap'n Arbyte) notes Roberts is just repeating himself in a timely fashion:
Others:
1/6/2004 11:09:57 AM
BY
Kevin
More Brancato Elsewhere In the near and intermediate future, I'll be posting about anything other than economics at Kikuchiyo News, hosted by Mr. Samuel Brown, a.k.a. Kikuchiyo. My first post at KN discusses Warren Brown, Washington DC, pork, and the new Volvo V50. I might be posting at KN in the distant future, or maybe not. Although economists can predict accurately the long-run effects of economic policies, we can't actually tell you what will happen in the long-run. Note the difference.
1/5/2004 03:24:33 PM
BY
Kevin
Nicer Estates for the Rich Lean Left notes a front-page Washington Post article about unprepared upper-middle class folks living in big estates in Loudoun county, Virginia. FYI, Loudoun has severe growth restrictions, meaning houses for rich people get built on large, or even massive estates, and houses for the poor don't get built at all. In the comments, I wrote that I have no idea why this article is on the front page, but I do think it's important in that it notes the actual consequences of the slow-growth initiatives passed in Loudoun--which have been to provide huge incentives for builders to provide rich pampered folks some very nice estates, while building little for middle-class and poor folks. Prices in the high-end DC metro market did not climb nearly as much as the markets for less luxurious accomodations. (In some areas, high-end prices were flat or seem to be declining. It's been the talk of the WaPO real estate pages for a while). These people need no sympathy, and could benefit from a little common sense and lot of the hard life. Don't these people know to that using a tractor or at least a quad with attachments will save them tons of time?
1/5/2004 01:46:55 PM
BY
Kevin
The New Afghan Constitution It's not easy to find, unfortunately. Why unfortunately ? Because it's a much better read than the EU constitution. The preamble is much better than I expected. Highlights of sections dealing with economics:
1/5/2004 12:42:38 PM
BY
Kevin
Empirical Evidence: Women Shop Longer, More Effectively Fascinating post by Tyler Cowen, in which he discusses gender differences and shopping. Tyler focuses on the human capital and opportunity costs of shopping, which are critical, but we must also examine the hidden personal benefits of shopping. I personally believe (through anecdotal evidence) that the main driver of gender inequality in shopping is the sheer pleasure and positive health effects that a lot of women get from the shopping experience. Don't get me wrong, some men I know also get such pleasure, but usually from car shopping and the like. As for me, I rather infrequently purchase an automobile as a gift. Unfortunately, disproving the "sheer pleasure" hypothesis is very difficult empirically. A social scientist would, in the end, have to make not only intrapersonal comparisons of "pleasure" before, during, and after shopping, but would also have to make interpersonal comparisons between men and women. UPDATE: I think, but can't be sure, that Stanley Crouch would agree with me:
1/5/2004 10:36:18 AM
BY
Kevin
Carnival of the Capitalists This week's Carnival of the Capitalists is up over at A Special Kind of Stupid. UPDATE: Econopundit notes, "With Instapundit linking to it this is redundant. Still, check out Carnival of the Capitalists."
1/5/2004 09:22:43 AM
BY
Kevin
Old-Tyme Health Insurance Dan Weintraub resurrects the old definition of health insurance:
(Hat tip: Prestopundit)
1/3/2004 03:48:21 PM
BY
Kevin
City Comforts
I've added some comments (here and here) to the discussions of "market failure" over at David Sucher's City Comforts Blog. What incited me to respond was this post:
"Market failure precedes regulation." Pithy way to put it by JM Roth. True? Seems likely to me and since it appears to be a matter of fact, it would a useful way to forward this discussion as it gives us something firm upon which to base our opinions....
In fact, by way of exception, can anyone think of a regulatory regime which has developed in the absenece of market failure.
To which I responded:
The discussion over Standard Oil, which I still believe was not your grandmother's monopoly, continues...
1/3/2004 03:28:54 PM
BY
Kevin
Consensus in Economic Forecasting Instapundit gave this Michael Crichton speech some needed public attention:
I've contended for a long time that all types of economic forecasting may be fun, and relatively highly rewarded, but they're not scientific endeavors. Still, when you read a "consensus" prediction of future movements in economic aggregates, what you are usually seeing is not, in fact, a consensus--i.e. an agreement among the parties involved. What you see with financial "consensus estimates" is a middle of a sample of forecasters--usually a median, sometimes an arithmetic mean. One definition goes like this:
How good is this median estimate? Well, Francis Galton showed could, within one percentage point, guess the dressed weight of an ox. How does it do otherwise? Compiling those results would be a life's work--and it's not going to be my life.
1/2/2004 05:54:42 PM
BY
Kevin
Optimal Cake-Cutting Before refrigeration, plastic wrap, and preservatives existed, some of the greatest scientific minds were busy figuring out a way to keep your symmetrical Christmas cakes from becoming dry, beacuse "the ordinary method of cutting out a wedge is very faulty." Sir Francis Galton recommended cutting out hunks from the middle of the cake, and squishing it back together. With care and precision, "The cuts shown on the figures represent those made with the intention of letting the cake last for three days."
1/1/2004 05:30:50 PM
|
|
|